April 9, 2018
By: |
Frank Cowell ; Brian Nolan ; Javier Olivera ; Philippe Van Kerm |
Although it is heartening to see wealth inequality being taken seriously, key concepts are often muddled, including the distinction between income and wealth, what is included in “wealth”, and facts about wealth distributions. This chapter highlights issues that arise in making ideas and facts about wealth inequality precise, and employs newly-available data to take a fresh look at wealth and wealth inequality in a comparative perspective. The composition of wealth is similar across countries, with housing wealth being the key asset. Wealth is considerably more unequally distributed than income, and it is distinctively so in the United States. Extending definitions to include pension wealth however reduces inequality substantially. Analysis also sheds light on life-cycle patterns and the role of inheritance. Discussion of the joint distributions of income and wealth suggests that interactions between increasing top income shares and the concentration of wealth and income from wealth towards the top is critical. |
Keywords: |
Inequality,Wealth,Income,Households,Inheritance,Top Incomes,Cross national,comparative |
URL: |
http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:lis:lwswps:24&r=ltv |
Leave a Comment » |
Uncategorized |
Permalink
Posted by maximorossi
April 9, 2018
By: |
Elisabeth Bublitz |
This paper investigates whether the individual misperception of income distributions helps explain why, opposite to Meltzer and Richard (1981), higher initial inequality levels do not correlate positively with redistribution. I conduct a representative survey experiment in Brazil, France, Germany, Russia, Spain, and the United States, providing a personalized information treatment on the income distribution to a randomly chosen subsample. Most respondents misperceive their own position in the income distribution. These biases di_er by country and the true income position. Misperceptions of the median income relate negatively to misperceived income positions, showing evidence for biased reference points. Correcting misperceptions slightly shifts the demand towards less redistribution in Germany and Russia which appears to be driven by respondents with a negative position bias. Apart from Spain and the US, treatment reactions lead to a convergence of the demand for redistribution across countries. The treatment also alters trust levels in government and beliefs about the importance of luck but not equally across bias types. |
Keywords: |
Income distribution, biased perceptions, inequality, survey experiment |
JEL: |
D31 D63 H20 |
URL: |
http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:lis:liswps:694&r=ltv |
Leave a Comment » |
Uncategorized |
Permalink
Posted by maximorossi
April 9, 2018
By: |
Brandolini, Andrea (Bank of Italy) ; Jenkins, Stephen P. (London School of Economics) ; Micklewright, John (University College London) |
Tony Atkinson is universally celebrated for his outstanding contributions to the measurement and analysis of inequality, but he never saw the study of inequality as a separate branch of economics. He was an economist in the classical sense, rejecting any sub-field labelling of his interests and expertise, and he made contributions right across economics. His death on 1 January 2017 deprived the world of both an intellectual giant and a deeply committed public servant in the broadest sense of the term. This collective tribute highlights the range, depth and importance of Tony’s enormous legacy, the product of over fifty years’ work. |
Keywords: |
Anthony B. Atkinson, inequality, poverty, public economics |
JEL: |
D3 H00 I3 |
URL: |
http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp10869&r=ltv |
Leave a Comment » |
Uncategorized |
Permalink
Posted by maximorossi
April 9, 2018
By: |
Cahuc, Pierre (Ecole Polytechnique, Paris) ; Carcillo, Stéphane (OECD) ; Minea, Andreea (Sciences Po, Paris) |
This paper investigates the effects of the labor market experience of high school dropouts four years after leaving school by sending fictitious résumés to real job postings in France. Compared to those who have stayed unemployed since leaving school, the callback rate is not raised for those with employment experience, whether it is subsidized or non-subsidized, in the market or non-market sector, if there is no training accompanied by skill certification. In particular, we find no stigma effect associated with subsidized or non-market sector work experience. Moreover, training accompanied by skill certification improves youth prospects only when the local unemployment rate is sufficiently low, which occurs in one fifth of the commuting zones only. |
Keywords: |
youth, unemployment, training |
JEL: |
J08 J60 |
URL: |
http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp10842&r=ltv |
Leave a Comment » |
Uncategorized |
Permalink
Posted by maximorossi
April 9, 2018
By: |
Burkhauser, Richard V. (Cornell University) ; Herault, Nicolas (Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research) ; Jenkins, Stephen P. (London School of Economics) ; Wilkins, Roger (Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research) |
Survey under-coverage of top incomes leads to bias in survey-based estimates of overall income inequality. Using income tax record data in combination with survey data is a potential approach to address the problem; we consider here the UK’s pioneering ‘SPI adjustment’ method that implements this idea. Since 1992, the principal income distribution series (reported annually in Households Below Average Income) has been based on household survey data in which the incomes of a small number of ‘very rich’ individuals are adjusted using information from ‘very rich’ individuals in personal income tax return data. We explain what the procedure involves, reveal the extent to which it addresses survey under-coverage of top incomes, and show how it affects estimates of overall income inequality. More generally, we assess whether the SPI adjustment is fit for purpose and consider whether variants of it could be employed by other countries. |
Keywords: |
inequality, income inequality, survey under-coverage, SPI adjustment, top incomes, tax return data, survey data |
JEL: |
D31 C81 |
URL: |
http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp10868&r=ltv |
Leave a Comment » |
Uncategorized |
Permalink
Posted by maximorossi
April 3, 2018
|
|
By: |
Angelo Antoci ; Fabio Sabatini |
There is growing evidence that face-to-face interaction is declining in many countries, exacerbating the phenomenon of social isolation. On the other hand, social interaction through online networking sites is steeply rising. To analyze these societal dynamics, we have built an evolutionary game model in which agents can choose between three strategies of social participation: 1) interaction via both online social networks and face-to-face encounters; 2) interaction by exclusive means of face-to-face encounters; 3) opting out from both forms of participation in pursuit of social isolation. We illustrate the dynamics of interaction among these three types of agent that the model predicts, in light of the empirical evidence provided by previous literature. We then assess their welfare implications. We show that when online interaction is less gratifying than offline encounters, the dynamics of agents’ rational choices of interaction will lead to the extinction of the sub-population of online networks users, thereby making Facebook and similar platforms disappear in the long run. Furthermore, we show that the higher the propensity for discrimination of those who interact via online social networks and via face-to-face encounters (i.e., their preference for the interaction with agents of their same type), the greater the probability will be that they all will end up choosing social isolation in the long run, making society fall into a “social poverty trap”. |
Keywords: |
Social networks; segregation; dynamics of social interaction; social media, social networking sites. |
JEL: |
C73 D85 O33 Z13 |
URL: |
http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:eei:rpaper:eeri_rp_2018_01&r=ltv |
Leave a Comment » |
Uncategorized |
Permalink
Posted by maximorossi
April 3, 2018
|
|
By: |
Chowdhury, Shyamal (University of Sydney) ; Sutter, Matthias (Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods) ; Zimmermann, Klaus F. (University of Bonn) |
Economic preferences – like time, risk and social preferences – have been shown to be very influential for real-life outcomes, such as educational achievements, labor market outcomes, or health status. We contribute to the recent literature that has examined how and when economic preferences are formed, putting particular emphasis on the role of intergenerational transmission of economic preferences within families. Our paper is the first to run incentivized experiments with fathers and mothers and their children by drawing on a unique dataset of 1,999 members of Bangladeshi families, including 911 children, aged 6-17 years, and 544 pairs of mothers and fathers. We find a large degree of intergenerational persistence as the economic preferences of mothers and fathers are significantly positively related to their children’s economic preferences. Importantly, we find that socio-economic status of a family has no explanatory power as soon as we control for parents’ economic preferences. A series of robustness checks deals with the role of older siblings, the similarity of parental preferences, and the average preferences within a child’s village. |
Keywords: |
intergenerational transmission of preferences, time preferences, risk preferences, social preferences, children, parents, Bangladesh, socio-economic status, experiment |
JEL: |
C90 D1 D90 D81 D64 J13 J24 J62 |
URL: |
http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp11337&r=ltv |
Leave a Comment » |
Uncategorized |
Permalink
Posted by maximorossi